The Clock and the Calendar: A Fundamental Confusion in Economic Thinking
- John-Michael Kuczynski
- Apr 11
- 3 min read
Have you ever wondered why economic predictions so often miss the mark? Or why central banks sometimes seem to be fighting yesterday's battles? It might come down to a conceptual error that's surprisingly simple yet profound: economists are trying to read the clock by averaging over the calendar.
The Mistake That's Costing Us Billions
A mathematician-turned-economist once pointed out a critical error that continues to plague economic policy: the confusion between instantaneous and non-instantaneous variables. This might sound technical, but it affects everything from interest rates to inflation control.
Let me break it down with an everyday example. Imagine you're driving from New York to Boston. Your speedometer shows your speed at any given moment (an instantaneous variable), while your trip computer shows your average speed for the entire journey (a non-instantaneous variable). You wouldn't look at your average speed for the whole trip to determine if you're speeding right now. Yet economists often make an analogous mistake.
Two Different Types of Economic Variables
Instantaneous variables are like snapshots:
Today's stock price
Current interest rates
The price of milk on your grocery receipt
Inflation at this exact moment
Non-instantaneous variables are more like movies:
GDP growth over a year
Unemployment rate for the last quarter
Inflation measured over 12 months
Consumer spending trends for a season
The problem arises when policymakers try to determine or control instantaneous conditions (like today's price level) using data that's averaged over time (like last year's GDP growth). It's like trying to determine your current speed by looking at how long your entire road trip took.
This Isn't Just an Academic Quibble
Physics figured this out long ago. Scientists don't try to determine a particle's exact position from its average location over time. They don't confuse instantaneous velocity with average speed.
But in economics, this confusion leads to real consequences:
Delayed Reactions: By the time a central bank responds to year-over-year inflation data, the actual economic conditions may have already changed dramatically.
Policy Mismatch: Applying tools designed for immediate impact based on long-term aggregates creates temporal disconnects in policy implementation.
Misleading Models: Economic models that don't properly distinguish between these variable types can appear accurate in retrospect but fail catastrophically in real-time prediction.
Real-World Example: Why Interest Rate Decisions Often Seem Behind the Curve
When the Federal Reserve decides to raise interest rates based on last quarter's GDP growth or year-over-year inflation, they're essentially trying to control today's economy using information that represents past conditions averaged over time.
This would be like adjusting your thermostat based on the average temperature of your house over the past week, rather than the current temperature. By the time you respond, conditions may have already changed significantly.
Moving Beyond the Confusion
The solution isn't necessarily more complex models or more data. It starts with conceptual clarity:
Proper Classification: Economists need to explicitly identify whether each variable in their models is instantaneous or non-instantaneous.
Temporal Alignment: Policies should match the time scale of the variables they target.
New Measurement Approaches: We need better ways to estimate truly instantaneous economic conditions, perhaps using high-frequency data and real-time indicators.
Why This Matters to You
Even if you're not an economist, this confusion affects your life. It influences interest rates on your mortgage, the value of your investments, and the broader economic conditions that impact your job security and purchasing power.
Understanding this distinction helps us become more critical consumers of economic news and predictions. The next time you hear that the Fed is making a decision based on last year's growth numbers, you'll understand why that might be problematic.
As the mathematician-economist so aptly put it, we need to stop "trying to read the clock by averaging over the calendar" if we want economic policy that truly responds to current conditions rather than shadows of the past.
What do you think? Have you noticed other examples where this confusion appears in economic discussions? Share your thoughts in the comments below.
Comments